Monday, December 30, 2019

The Prevalence Of Mental Health Disorders - 1335 Words

The prevalence of mental health disorders in the Unites States is growing exponentially. According to the Center for Disease Control (2015), one out of five adolescents are diagnosed with a mental health disorder and 15 million children are estimated with a mental health diagnosis. Having resources available to this population from the advanced schools of psychology is vital to maintaining healthy interventions for our future children and adolescents. Furthermore, it’s imperative to review not only the diagnosis of the children experiencing mental health systems, but to also review systemically the entire health spectrum of the child’s wellness and deficiencies. According the American Psychological Association (2017), these levels can†¦show more content†¦Specifically, these collaborative efforts included: the review and completion of paperwork such as the informed consent, explaining the limits of confidentiality, and the process related to completing the learning conversation. Contacting the parents before the meeting to develop an initial or pre-assessment of the child’s and adolescent’s interests and topics in addition to real-life interaction with children and adolescents was purposeful in completing the interviews towards experience in working with these populations. Participant and Question Selection Process The selection process of choosing participants for this assignment focused on a set criterion necessary for a productive learning conversation. The participants that I chose were cousins that I don’t see often since they live very far away and we typically don’t keep in contact with each other. In the initial request for the learning conversation permission, I called the participants home. I proceeded to explain the project to the parents, child, and adolescent. My interviewees were siblings and both of them and the parents verbally agreed to participating in the learning conversation. The participants were representative of a convenience sample since both were available to be interviewed on the same day. After selecting my participants and having an initial assessment from the parents, I began to look at the process of selecting questions. IShow MoreRelatedDescriptive Epidemiology Of Major Depressive Disorder In Canada1111 Words   |  5 Pagesat the data regarding Major Depressive Disorder (MDD) and Bipolar Disorder (BD) from four countries and compared it with the data from the United States. The countries are Canada, United Kingdom, Australia and Mexico. For Canada, we referred to the study Descriptive Epidemiology of Major Depressive Disorder in Canada in 2012. In this study, they used a survey called Canadian Community Health Study - Mental Health (CCHS-MH) to evaluate Major Depressive Disorder among their participants. CCHS-MH is anRead MoreMental Illness Of Mental Health Disorders1590 Words   |  7 Pagessomewhat reliable evidence has been gathered on mental illnesses and their prevalence. Before around the 1980’s though, the evidence that was gathered on mental ill nesses was too inconsistent to be credible. In a survey conducted by the World Health Organization’s department of World Mental Health, data was gathered on the prevalence of mental health disorders in 14 countries around the world. The results of these surveys conclude that mental health disorders are more prevalent than any other chronic illnessRead MoreThe Prevalence of Co-Occurring Disorders Essay893 Words   |  4 Pageshead: THE PREVALENCE OF CO-OCCURRING DISORDERS The Prevalence of Co-Occurring Disorders Launita D. Joseph Grand Canyon University August 15, 2012 The Prevalence of Co-Occurring Disorders When a counselor has a new client they are working with, the client has to be assessed. When being assessed the counselor has to determine what issues the client may have. Through being assessed, the counselor may come to realize the client has more than one issue which is called co-occurring disorders. At thisRead MoreCommon Mental Disorders in Colombian Women1590 Words   |  7 PagesThe common mental disorders represent a major public health problem. The prevalence of common mental disorders varies according to the method of evaluation, either with the use of a scale or conducting an interview. The prevalence of common mental disorders is almost 25%, if it is used the General Health Questionnaire (GHQ-12).1 Common mental disorders are more frequent among women than men; it seems that women are more sensitive to stressors. Around the world, common mental disorders produce a negativeRead MoreThe Prevalence Of Mental Illness1348 Words   |  6 PagesMental illness is increasingly b eing recognized as a challenge faced by many Canadians. The Mental Health Strategy for Canada estimates that ‘in any given year, one in five people in Canada experiences a mental health problem or illness’. (Bartram et al., 2012) The prevalence of mental illness is not exclusive to the Canadian population and it is estimated that these figures are rising. In 2004, the World Health Organization ranked major depression as third in terms of the overall burden of diseasesRead MoreAutism Is A Matter Of Passionate National Debate1197 Words   |  5 Pageschanged from being a condition nobody had even heard about to widely recognized mental health condition. Due to widespread use of internet, social media and smartphones everybody knows something about autism. Just searching for autism in Google brings up more than 68 million results. Autism has become a matter of passionate national debate among different stake holders such as government, public health agencies, mental healt h associations, non-profit organizations, parents of autistic people and publicRead MoreSymptoms And Factors Of Schizophrenia1344 Words   |  6 PagesThis assignment will provide a definition about schizophrenia, its symptoms and factors that may cause it briefly as well as its incidence and prevalence in Australia, Spain and United States of America. It also introduces some of old and recent treatments of this disease. 2.0 Definition of Schizophrenia Schizophrenia is categorised as a psychotic disorder. Psychosis-a general word that is usually used as the psychotic illnesses syndromes-affects people’s thoughts, speech and sense of reality. MostRead MorePost Traumatic Stress1171 Words   |  5 PagesRunning head: MENTAL HEALTH: THE AFRICAN AMERICAN PERSPECTIVE Running head: MENTAL HEALTH: THE AFRICAN AMERICAN PERSPECTIVE 2 African Americans living in urban, low-income, impoverished environments are at high risk for exposure to traumatic events, and have a potential prevalence of Posttraumatic Stress Disorder (PTSD) due to previous and repeated trauma exposure. African-Americans living in urban, low income communities with continuous exposure to communityRead MoreThe Effects Of Mental Health And Depression747 Words   |  3 PagesIntroduction According to a recent study by the National Institute of Mental Health, it was revealed that 13% of African American women suffer from depression at some point in their life, a number higher than the general population (Ward, Wiltshire, Detry, Brown, 2013). Mood and Anxiety disorders such as Depression are experienced by black women from all walks of life, especially those from low Socioeconomic backgrounds. Due to a variety of factors Black women are more likely to report psychologicalRead MoreMental Disorders Among Geriatrics Are One Of The Most Costly Public Health Dilemmas1055 Words   |  5 PagesABSTRACT Mental disorders among geriatrics are one of the most costly public health dilemmas. Depression, suicidal behavior, and Alzheimer’s are just a few common mental illnesses the elderly suffers from. According to the Center for Disease Control and Prevention the number of older adults with mental illnesses is predicted to incline drastically. The growth of the population, has caused a burden on numerous healthcare facilities in America and many elderly individuals are less likely to seek

Sunday, December 22, 2019

Community Policing in Canada Essay - 908 Words

Community Policing in Canada Community policing is a relatively new model of service delivery that is employed by the majority of police forces across Canada. Community policing however, is not a â€Å"new† approach, it is more correctly a renewal or re-emergence of the old approach developed in Metropolitan London (Leighton Normandeau, p.21). The amendments to the current system are evident in Leighton Normandeau’s (1990) review of the future of community policing. The ideas behind the move to community policing was; â€Å"a vision in which the ultimate consumers of police services, the citizens themselves, have input into the setting of priorities by their local department and play an active role in dealing with crime and†¦show more content†¦al). An eye-opener that called for a serious re-evaluation of the current service became evident in a review of incoming calls, â€Å"in 1991, 60,000 calls to the police complaint line were abandoned by citizens prior to being answered. Many of these callers, in an attempt to contact the police, then called the 911 emergency line, tying up this emergency system (Griffiths et al., p.241)†. The re-evaluation of the service, lead to necessary changes and improvements being made, which resulted in the EPS adopting the model of community policing in their area. The success of implementing a program like this requires that both parties be well informed and well educated on the changes that will take place. One of the first steps is to market the concept of community policing both internally (within the department), as well as externally(within the community). Marketing community policing internally often involves collapsing the existing structures of authority that are in place as well as the specialization within the department. The case study mentioned that although the senior administrators in the department played a critical role in the reform, it was also necessary that line level officers be active participants in the process. After all, two important components of community policing are empowerment and ownership. Officers were given ownership of certain areas that wereShow MoreRelatedMulticulturalism Is The Fundamental Act That All Residents Are Equal1043 Words   |  5 Pagesfrom a different background of religion, caste, color, knowledge in one country. Canada is the multicultural country where different people from a different culture or ethnic living together. Canada’s official policy establishes the multiculturalism where Canada gives equal respect to all religion, racial and cultural background. Canada is the multicultural nation who receives immigrants from different cultures. Canada multiculturalism act is the fundamental act that all residents are equal. MulticulturalismRead MoreCommunity Policing And Public Security1415 Words   |  6 Pages Topic: Community Policing Name Affiliated institute â€Æ' In every corner of the world, security to the public has always been a concern. It is a responsibility of the government to provide security to its people. To ensure that there is a reliable security to the public, the government must streamline some approaches to security threats and effectively prevent or counter them. It is a common understanding that in most of the times in our lives, we happen to interact with the people who breakRead MorePolice Agencies Implement Community Policing, And Problem Oriented Policing Essay1357 Words   |  6 Pagesagencies implement community policing, and problem oriented policing? and if so do they work? In this paper, this paper will examine the two different styles of policing in a contemporary society. Community policing where the main emphasis is that the police and the community work together on issues, and problem-oriented policing where the police try and understand specific issues within the community. It will also examine several exampl es of different policing agencies in Canada, and what they implementRead MoreThe Impact Of Canadian Policing During The Nineteenth Century895 Words   |  4 Pagesof police work in Canada. A number of events have shaped Canadian policing, and in particular have shaped three different kinds. These are municipal, provincial, and federal police services. All these services had to start from somewhere. â€Å"In many respects, the emergence of Canadian policing during the nineteenth century closely mirrored the development of punishment and corrections† (Griffiths 2004). In the earliest days, policing in communities was carried out by community residents. Later, someRead MoreCrime And Crime : The Criminal Justice System Essay1520 Words   |  7 Pagesnot some criminal justice personnel adhere to proper administration of justice and rule of law. One such agent is police officers and the notion of policing. The notion or idea of policing and roles of police officers spark debate as to how policing is carried out not only within legal processes of the criminal justice system but also within community settings and environments. This paper argues that the criminal justice system manifests entities hinder effective administration of justice in criminalRead MoreTrends In Ala Essay1708 Words   |  7 PagesIntroduction The Province of Alberta has been moving towards more of a community based policing style. This style integrates the officers into society rather than a separate entity, allowing them to be more involved and have direct interaction with the citizens. Numerous trends and challenges have emerged in the recent years in Alberta, which continue to affect the way the police deal with the issues. In 2010, Frank Oberle, the Solicitor General, set out framework to guide police officers and otherRead MorePolicing : Proactive And Proactive Policing Essay758 Words   |  4 PagesPolicing is a huge contributor to maintaining peace and order in Canada. Without it, there would be huge amounts of violence and chaos in society. Different types of policing has been created and tested such as; reactive, preventive, and proactive policing. Proactive policing has proven to be the most effective type of policing in preventing and deterring crime. â€Å"Proactive policing is the practice of deterring crim inal activity by showing police presence and engaging the public to learn their concernsRead MoreAssignment #2 – Policing a Modern Society600 Words   |  3 Pages#2 – Policing a Modern Society Introduction Traditionally, policing has proven to have its limits. The arrests did not deter criminals, there was no impact on the crime rate, and policing was a very reactive practise. Obviously, something needed to change. With policing a modern society, there are a number of different techniques that can be displayed, and prove to be beneficial. However; in this essay I will attempt to showcase two very important, and alike styles; Problem oriented policing, andRead More Evolution of the Police Officer Essays1570 Words   |  7 Pagesserve and protect the people in their community. The earliest police force was established around the 1750’s. Although the first police force in the modern sense came to be over 250 years ago, the purpose they had is the same as today. As with the rest of the world advancing and progressing, the police force has advanced in many ways which have made them a more efficient and capable unit, in order to more fully accomplish their purpose of serving their co mmunity. In the next few paragraphs you willRead MoreCommunity Policing Is Defined As The System Of Allocating Police Officers Essay1063 Words   |  5 PagesJustice Capstone â€Æ' Community policing is defined as the system of allocating police officers to particular areas so that they become familiar with the local inhabitants. Many communities have at least one officer assigned to patrol their area and tend to the people living within the area. These community policing officers take notice of the area and learn the ins and outs of these neighborhoods and surrounding areas. The officer familiarizes themselves with the people in the community and builds a strong

Saturday, December 14, 2019

Theories on Resource Curse Free Essays

Introduction The resource curse or excess availability of natural resources presents a particularly interesting analysis when it comes to economics and often underpins many of the policies and theories which can be looked at in relation to how the government can organise its own economic behaviour, so as to achieve long-term economic growth (Acemoglu, 1996). The purpose of this section of the literature review is to look at factors associated with the resource curse. In particular, the explanations of the resource curse and the way in which they may potentially be dealt will be examined, before putting the resource curse into context and then discussing measurement techniques and policy approaches and looking specifically at how these may be used in relation to the resource curse in Libya. We will write a custom essay sample on Theories on Resource Curse or any similar topic only for you Order Now Crucially, it is noted that there is empirical data to suggest that countries with a higher level of natural resources were also seen to be displaying trends of low economic growth (Alexeev and Conrad, 2009). This seemingly presents a potentially interesting point of analysis for those involved in developing policies that will enable a country with a high level of natural resource to achieve a better level of economic growth as a result (Alexeev and Conrad, 2009). In the leading research undertaken by Sachs and Warner (1995, 1999, 2001), it was shown that any nation with very high levels of natural resources would typically find that it has lower economic growth, particularly when the figures are looked at in a whilst taking into account demographic, economic or political differences. At the outset, the work by Sachs and Warner, in 1995, aimed to look at the seeming anomaly that countries with a high level of a specific resource were performing poorly, in terms of economic growth (Michaels, 2011). This issue was later the focus of many different areas of research, with specific case studies being used as a means of establishing why these natural resources were ultimately having a negative impact on overall economic growth. As a result of this, several theories emerged over the years as to why precisely the resource curse has evolved and whether there are different ways in which resources can be viewed so as to potentially reduce the impact of such natural resource excess in a country such as Libya (Bleaney and Nishiyama, 2002). The concept that natural resources may become what was seen to be an economic curse emerged during the 1980s, with the actual terminology â€Å"resource curse† first being used in 1993 (Sachs and Warner, 1995). These theories essentially created an analysis of a counterintuitive situation whereby it was shown that countries with a high level of natural resource were not developing economic growth at the expected rate. A wide variety of studies, notably those by Sachs and Warner (1995) aimed to show the link between natural resources and economic growth, which then led to a wide variety of studies on precisely why this negative relationship appeared to exist (Mauro, 1995). As a result, a wide variety of different theories have been used as a means of describing why this relationship exists. Theories of Resource Curse Although there have been various research projects looking at specific explanations of the resource curse, which will be looked at in more detail below, there has also been a body of research which has looked more generally at the theories of resources and why such situations have emerged, in the first place. Each of these factors will be looked at in turn; however, a brief overview of the theory will provide strong background understanding. Dutch Disease One of the leading explanations to be presented in relation to the resource curse theory is that of the â€Å"Dutch Disease† theory established by Matsuyama (1992), which argues that when an organisation or country specialises in a particular type of resource production, the combination of the specialisation as well as the appreciation of the exchange rate will then result in a decline and will become more conducive to other industries which are not going to lead to the same economic growth (Lutz, 1994). Fundamentally, it is argued that this type of resource curse can lead to other factors such as the industrial sector generally lagging behind as they are not the main driving force within the economy (Fosu, 1996). The underlying notion of this theory is that the level of expansion experienced as a result of the use of natural resources is not going to be large enough to offset the negative effect of failure to industrialise other sectors in order to support central economic growth within the relevant industrial sector. Furthermore, this type of reliance on natural resources can impact on the way in which exports are treated within countries with a high level of natural resources which will be looking towards exporting these natural resources and may even do so in preference to other exports, which could ultimately improve economic growth (Papyrakis and Gerlagh. 2007). The empirical example which was used during the development of the Dutch Disease concept was used by The Economist, in 1977, when it looked towards explaining why there had been such a dramatic decline in the manufacturing sector across the Netherlands, since natural oil fields had been found eighteen years earlier. Research in the area of the Dutch Disease concept has focused on a situation whereby there has been a natural resource discovery, although it is noted that this could potentially be used as the same concept when there is any large inflow of foreign currency. For example, it could be due to substantial foreign investment or a large amount of assistance from abroad (Manzano and Rigobon, 2006). The classical version of Dutch Disease was developed by Corden and Neary (1982), although it is noted that the actual terminology was used previously by The Economist, five years earlier, showing that the notion of Dutch Disease had been in place for several years, even if the underlying reasons and theoretical analysis took a while in being formulated. During the analysis in 1982, the research took on board the fact that certain booming sectors, such as the extraction of oil or the extraction of natural gases, are looked at alongside the lagging sectors, which would seem to be the manufacturing sectors, but also referred to other sectors, such as agriculture, depending on the nature of the country in question (Lederman, and Maloney 2003). However, the fundamentals of the research suggested that there was a booming sector and a lagging sector and again this supports the idea that, although the issues associated with the Dutch Disease have focused on a natural resource boom, including the underlying reason for an economic boom in a given sector (Sala-i-Martin and Subramanian, 2003). During this initial research, it was found that the level of resources can affect the quality of that country, in specific ways. The first being the resource movement affect whereby the resource boom increases demand for labour in that particular sector and labour is therefore diverted away from other sectors into the booming sector. The actual impact of this effect can be variable, depending on the nature of the sectors involved, where the lagging sector has not historically employed a large number of people. The second effect is that of the spending effect, which occurs as a result of the dramatic increase in resources being brought forward by the boom, in any given sector. Moreover, where there is an increased demand for certain non-traded goods, the price of the goods involved will then increase. Despite this, the prices in these sectors are set on an international basis and therefore cannot change, thus causing an increase in the real exchange rate within the country (Sala-i-Mar tin and Subramanian, 2003). Given the potential merit of this argument presented in a relatively rudimentary form, back in the early 1980s, several models of international trade have looked to develop this notion in a bid either to support or disprove the argument that the Dutch Disease theory can be used to explain why resources emerge in countries, such as Libya (Meier and Rauch, 2000). When looking at basic resource-based international trade models, it can be argued that a country will typically specialise in whichever industries have a competitive advantage within the relevant country which is particularly rich in one or more natural resources and which, according to international trade models, would be better off specialising in the extraction and sale of these natural resources. Despite the seeming conflict with these international trade models, theories have been developed around this international trade body, which suggests that specialisation to this extent could be detrimental. For example, where the natural resource begins to dwindle and where there is a downturn in prices, the country cannot then adapt and refocus on the now lagging industries, at a rate which would make it commercially viable. Investment may also be slow from firms, particularly in the lagging sectors, which then creates an even greater gap between the booming and lagging sectors. Research in this area has looked not only at the effect, but also at the large amount of expertise involved in focusing on minimising the impact of Dutch Disease, looking at specific examples of this type of scenario, in a bid to consider how countries such as Libya can look to minimise the effect of Dutch Disease theory, if it begins to emerge within their jurisdiction (Stern, 2008). According to existing research, there are two key ways in which threats associated with the Dutch disease can be reduced. Firstly, the country can look towards slowing down the appreciation of the real exchange rate; and secondly, it can take measures towards boosting the way in which the lagging sector is operating, from a competitive point of view (Auty 2001). For example, the country could attempt to neutralise the revenues from the boom sector by ensuring that not all of the revenues are brought into the country, at once. By maintaining the revenues in some form of funds abroad and then bringing them into the country slowly, this will then reduce the negative effect discussed above, and will reduce the impact on the real exchange rate. This approach can be politically unpopular, as these types of resource booms are often seen as a means of alleviating economic harm in the region, such as poverty. It can also be difficult from a political point of view for those in charge of finan cial resources, at a particular point in time, whowish to secure the future of the government and will typically aim to have a legacy of success and will therefore want to utilise the financial resources available to them. Despite this, there are several examples of these types of wealth funds, such as the government pension fund in Norway, the state oil fund of Azerbaijan and the Future Generations fund, which was established in the state of Kuwait, back in 1976 (Barbier, 2005). The second approach, which is to improve the competitiveness of other sectors, can be done through government investment in specific areas of infrastructure. Linked to this can be the approach of protectionism, although this can potentially worsen the effect of Dutch Disease. This therefore requires careful consideration by the government as to how it is going to protect the lagging sector in such a way that does not result in a false market which is simply not sustainable in the long run (Mehlum et al 2006). Finally, although the existence of Dutch Disease has been readily accepted by various theorists in this area, difficulties do emerge when it comes to actually diagnosing whether or not a particular country is subject to Dutch Disease, at that point in time. Accordingly, improving the relationship between the increase in a particular natural resource and a decline in another sector and a change in the real exchange rate can be difficult, as these trends may actually emerge over a long period in time (Ross, 2001). For example, the Balassa-Samuelson effect refers to the situation whereby productivity increases and has an impact on real exchange rate, this will only go a small way towards explaining and diagnosing whether Dutch Disease is being experienced in an individual country, at that point in time. Even when looking at the location in which the concept of Dutch Disease has emerged in the Netherlands, there is still some debate amongst economists that the decline of the manufacturin g industry in the Netherlands was actually caused by the level of spending on social services and not by a natural resource curse at all. Establishing this link can therefore be a particularly difficult element of diagnosing the Disease and can therefore be a barrier towards putting in place suitable policies to mitigate, or even remove, the impact of Dutch Disease when it does occur (Davis, 2003). As well as the concept of Dutch Disease, there are multiple other factors which could potentially go some way towards explaining the existence of the resource curse, all of which have their own potential merit attached to them. Political Conflict Where a country has an immediate need for economic income often provokes conflict within society, while each entity looks to gain the most out of the natural resources that have been discovered. Conflict is obvious in some jurisdictions, with groups of people openly competing over the natural resources in their region. In many cases, the conflict can be somewhat hidden, with different groups within society all competing secretly for budgetary allocation from the government, thus creating a situation whereby the government finds it harder to operate effectively and is consistently navigating conflict between the various groups (Bannon and Colllier,2003). This theory suggests that a country with a large amount of natural resources may be more susceptible to internal and political conflict. This, in turn, can cause difficulties for the government, when it comes to establishing a strong economic performance and a suitably robust governance structure. For example, research by Bannon and C olllier, in 2003 , suggested that where a country has commodity exports which make up approximately 25% of gross domestic product, it then has a 33% risk of internal political conflict, whereas if it exports just 5% of gross domestic product, the expectation of internal conflict reduces to just 6%. Similarly, research in the area of the resource curse has shown a tendency of naturally rich resource countries to become involved in international conflict, or indeed to be the target of international conflict (Stijns, 2005). Specific examples in recent times include Iran and Kuwait, as well as Libya which has become involved in disputes with its neighbouring region of Chad. Whilst the direct link between international conflict and natural resources remains relatively unproven, the continuous unease within the relationship between Western powers and oil-rich states is evident and certainly supports at least some arguments that a state with a large amount of natural resources will be more susceptible to becoming involved in international conflict. Rent Seeking Further theoretical background that has emerged in the area of the resource curse is that of rent seeking, suggesting that this can be used as a means of ascertaining why there is a negative growth where there is also an abundance of natural resources (Robinson et al., 2006). Rent seeking behaviour, refers to the situation whereby an individual or a particular firm will look towards increasing their own share of wealth available within the country, without necessarily increasing the overall level of wealth experienced by the country as a whole (Baland and Francois, 2000) This can typically be achieved by manipulating regulatory agencies or trying to gain some form of advantage in the market, while placing others at a competitive disadvantage. This type of rent seeking behaviour, particularly from those involved in a high level of management of natural resources can then create a situation whereby those individuals benefit and the overall country does not (Papyrakis and Gerlagh, 2004) . The concept of rent seeking was developed in 1974 by Krueger and, although the modern rent seeking behaviours have little to do with the payment of a lease or property rental, but rather looking at the way in which profits and wages are divided across groups of individuals, by referring to the ways in which they control natural resources. Rent seeking behaviour refers to the attempt by an individual to obtain a proportion of income which is not reflective of their fair portion, by manipulating the environment around them, either socially or economically, in order to extract an excess rent from their activities. This is often seen to be inherently linked to the concept of corruption. Furthermore, where there is an abundance of natural resource being held within the hands of this type of individual, rent seeking behaviour becomes harmful and can result in a monopolistic power being held by a small group of individuals, without necessarily benefiting the overall welfare of the state (To rvik 2002). By looking at the theories associated with rent seeking behaviour, there are substantial negative consequences, which can emerge and could go some way towards explaining why the resource curse can become extremely influential within certain regions. From a theoretical point of view, there is a substantial moral hazard associated with rent seeking behaviour. For example, when individual entrepreneurial tycoons within the natural resource industry are in a position where they can purchase a better regulatory environment at a cheaper rate than they would be able to otherwise, in order improve efficiency within their own operations, there is an incentive to opt towards corruption. This might involve purchasing the regulatory environment that they wish, rather than focusing on becoming more efficient, which would ultimately benefit the whole industry. Where this type of scenario emerges, there is a strong argument that rent seeking behaviour of this nature can potentially have a detriment al impact on the overall production within states. This is because rent seeking behaviour is inherently linked to the reaction of the government and situations which may be deemed to be poor governance and corruption. Rent seeking behaviour in itself, therefore, cannot be used as an explanation for the resource curse. Furthermore, it has been argued by economists, such as Stigilz (2012), that rent seeking behaviour can be used to explain how social inequality of income earners’ living standards emerge in certain countries or regions within countries. Again, whilst this is not directly linked to the rent seeking behaviour causing the resource curse, by taking this theory one step further, it can be argued that rent seeking behaviour creates inequality, whether this be inequality of income for individuals in a country or inequality for the treatment of particular trade sectors, e.g. inequality between the natural resources and the other industries such as manufacturing. Corruption / Governance Issues Volatility within natural resources can create particular challenges for the government in any country where natural resources are the dominant source of income. Simply looking at the price fluctuation of crude oil over the last few decades, it can be seen that the price of crude oil has gone as low as three dollars per barrel and has gone up as high as $145 per barrel. This type of volatility can make it very difficult for any government, or indeed private organisation, to manage its investment and production policies so as to maximise the potential wealth available. When relying on one specific natural resource such as oil or gas that is subject to international price volatility, it can be particularly difficult when it comes to planning debt services in dealing with government planning (Davis, 2003). Even where the government is being astute and transparent, it simply does not have a crystal ball and cannot predict the future in a way that would enable it to hedge bets or to smoot h out any income volatility as a result of the international market (Davis, 2001). Linked to this is the danger that the government will enter into agreements for excessive borrowing, based on the notion that the income will continue to be lucrative and in order to support or improve an aspect of the country such as health of education (Fatas and Mihov, 2003). It may have been prudent at the point at which the debt was taken out, as sudden changes in prices and volatility within the market soon create a situation whereby the government is unable to service the debt it has have entered into. In particular, this was seen to cause problems in Nigeria and Venezuela, where the governments rapidly expanded their level of debt on the back of the oil boom of the 1970s, but then when oil prices dropped in the 1980s, this meant that the governments could no longer make the repayments and the debt spiralled out of control (Fosu, 1996). In a similar way, corruption is perceived to be a potentially strong explanatory factor as to why countries with a large amount of natural resources find themselves with relatively low economic growth, overall (Fosu, 1996). In order for economic policies and growth to be used to assist in this way for long-term growth there has to be a relatively high level of transparent governance. To a large extent, it can be seen as easier to maintain authority through ensuring that resources are allocated to the dominant parties, i.e. those involved in the natural resource industry. As such, the need to build up other infrastructures, such as governance of the other sectors, has notably diminished and the regulatory structure that underlies the economy becomes underdeveloped and unable to deal with the level of income being derived. Corruption within the political parties is also becoming an issue where there is a resource rich country and the politicians are providing for themselves and not the general economy. With offshore tax havens being readily available, politicians are able to conceal this type of commercial gain to such an extent that it simply is not sufficiently transparent (Van der Ploeg, and Poelhekke, 2010). This concern was the subject of a report written by the United States Senate Foreign Relations Committee, titled â€Å"Petroleum and Poverty Paradox†. In this report, it was stated that: â€Å"too often, oil money that should go to a nation’s poor ends up in the pockets of the rich, or it may be squandered on grand palaces and massive showcase projects instead of being invested productively†. Lack of Diversification / Lack of Development of Further Resources Finally, there is also a body of research which suggests that the resource curse can be attributed to the lack of attention and investment placed on other sectors (Cotet and Tsui, 2010). More specifically, when the region is producing such a large income stream, naturally, it can be tempting to ignore other areas, and in certain developing countries, the government in question will often rely heavily on the income being derived from natural resources, without planning for the future by developing the infrastructure in such a way that other factors can also evolve alongside the natural resource boom. Also, as it is relatively common for these natural resource industries to achieve a large amount of financial return, but not necessarily to provide a large amount of jobs, it can be the case that education and intellectual knowledge is disregarded (Ding, and Field, 2005). Furthermore, when looking at the human resource element, it can be seen that the natural resources industries will ty pically pay a much higher salary and this will typically attract the more able individuals within the economy to focus on this particular natural resource industry (Ding, and Field, 2005). As a result, many of the more educated individuals who would be capable of showing entrepreneurial activity within other industries may be diverted from the original course of action, in order to hopefully obtain higher salaries within the natural resource industry. This can result in some form of â€Å"brain drain† within the other industries, as more capable individuals naturally gravitate towards the higher paying salaries. As the natural resource industry begins to decline, this creates a real problem for the country, as a whole, because there is insufficient expertise present in the other industries to ensure that they can then develop to such an extent that the overall economy does not suffer (Gylfason, 2001). Resource Curse in Libya Having looked at the various different theories behind the resource curse and in a bid to ascertain whether or not the link between economic growth and high natural resources is somewhat accidental, or based on solid theories, it is helpful to consider the position specifically in Libya. The research theories above go some way towards potentially explaining the existence of the resource curse; however, undertaking a more detailed look at the situation in Libya should offer additional explanatory research as to how the resource curse evolves on a practical level. Research into the position in Libya is clearly important in the context of the wider research being undertaken here. However, it needs to be borne in mind that many of the reports emanating from Libya are likely to be driven by some form of political overtones and therefore there is a need to look at the situation in this context, in order to offer a higher level of objectivity (Tsui, 2011). Reports have suggested that it was grievances and social/economic unrest that actually lead to the revolution experienced in Libya in recent years. Oil resources in the region have allowed the country to accumulate naturally high levels of wealth which have resulted in many of the concerns listed above relating to the resource curse from a theoretical point of view. By the mid-1970s, Libya had an economy that was extremely focused on oil, with a lack of diversification into other sectors and industries, something which is seen to be inherent in the problems and the explanation provided for the lack of economic growth, despite a high level of natural resources (Dollar and Kraay, 2001). Although the upward spiral due to large oil resources remained as a central part of the Libyan economy growth for over 40 years, the revolution clearly demonstrates many of the key components identified as part of the resource curse above. When looking at the situation in Libya, it has been argued that issues of corruption and weak governance has been seen to be central in creating the revolution, which effectively ended the boom period in Libya (Smith, 1976). When looking at the difficulties faced by Libya, in recent years, several different explanations have been provided, many of which are very similar to those used to explain when looking at the resources curse as a more general concept. For example, the development of human capital has become very much centred on the oil industry. This has created a large amount of inequality between those individuals who are sufficiently educated to engage with the oil industry and those who are not. This type of display in inequality has resul ted in an extremely under-developed economy in all aspects other than the oil industry itself (Wheeler, 1984). Unsurprisingly, the dramatic decline and revolution in Libya, in recent years, has created much discussion about how Libya could potentially resolve the situation and place the country in a stronger position, going forward. If it were true to accept that Libya had suffered from a resource curse, it is likely that the resolution can also be found by looking at how other jurisdictions have dealt with their resources and the options available to them. One body of research, for example, has looked at whether or not the Alaskan solution could potentially offer opportunities for Libya in the aftermath of the civil crisis. According to the Alaskan Governor, in 1982, the key problem that the region faced was the lack of check and balance over how oil revenue was used, suggesting that this was the underlying reason for the high level of resources becoming a curse and not a benefit. With no control over how the income from the oil revenues is used, the key determinants for the resource curse can be seen to be experienced. For example, a high level of corruption was experienced within the political groups, all of whom were attempting to divert the natural resource revenues for their own gain. By allowing these types of diversions to take place, other industries failed to gain the investments necessary and the industry soon began to lack in both financial and human capital. By looking at the Alaskan situation, the problem being faced in Libya can be attributed almost entirely to the fact that the revenue streams were diverted to politicians and not used for the foundation of the country or for developing a general stability within the economy, so that other industries would not lag behind and where the country would be in a position to deal with long-term development from the short-term income gain (Leite and Weidmann, 2002). By taking this on board, it is argued that the key development for Libya, going forward, is the need to focus on ensuring that the income derived as a short-term gain, in this case from oil revenues, (although it could be in relation to any other form of short-term and immediate gain) is subsequently invested for the long-term. This would mean that the government is effectively forced into investing the wealth in a more objective and fair way. This argument, however, is linked to the notion that, although a high level of resource has been seen to be directly correlated to low economic growth, it is not clear whether it is a case of the actual natural resources causing the low growth, or whether it is the economic and political conditions that often emerge as a result of a booming natural resource that create the knock-on effect of low growth. It is this area of questioning that remains open for further discussion and will be relevant when it comes to determining how Libya should now look towards improving its position in the long run. In order to break the cycle, the actual pattern of the cycle first needs to be understood. Conclusion The issue of resources and the empirical evidence that links countries which have high natural resources with low economic growth has been established in multiple different previous research papers. What is not as clear, however, is where the resource curse emanates from and in this respect there is a distinct gap in the literature, particularly in relation to the position in Libya. Therefore, in order to establish how, having suffered from the negative repercussions of the perceived resource curse in Libya, or indeed in any other jurisdiction, and to make sure that they do not suffer from a similar fate in future, this research needs to start by identifying the root cause of the problem. The resource curse is not simply a case of cause and effect that can be easily mapped, with several potential interventions necessary to improve the overall economic conditions in similar countries, going forward References Acemoglu, D., (1995). Reward Structures and the Allocation of Talent. European Economic Review 39(1), 17-33. Acemoglu, D. (1996). â€Å"A Micro foundation for Social Increasing Returns in Human Capital Accumulation.† Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111(3), 779-804. Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., Robinson, J. and Thaicharoen, Y. (2003). ‘Institutional causes, macroeconomic symptoms: volatility, crises and growth’, Journal of Monetary Economics, 50(1), 49-123. Acemoglu, D., and Robinson, J.A., (2006). Economic backwardness in political perspective. American Political Science Review 100(1), 115-131. Alexeev, M. and Conrad, R. (2009). ‘The elusive curse of oil’, Review of Economics and Statistics, 91(3), 586-598. Atkinson, G. and Hamilton, K. (2003). ‘Savings, growth and the resource curse hypothesis’,World Development, 31(11), 1793–1807. Auty R.M. (1990). Resource-based industrialization: sowing the oil in eight developing countries. Clarendon, Oxford. Auty R.M. (1991). Managing mineral dependence: Papua New Guinea 1972–89. Natural Resources Forum, 90–99. Auty, R. (1994). â€Å"Industrial Policy Reform in Six Newly Industrializing Countries: The Resource Curse Thesis.† World Development, 22(1), 1165-1171. Auty, R. (2001). Resource Abundance and Economic Development. Oxford University Press, Oxford. Baland J.M., Francois, P. (2000). Rent Seeking and Resource Booms. Journal of Development Economics 61(2), 527-42. Barbier, E. (2005). Natural Resources and Economic Development. Cambridge University Press, New York and Cambridge. Barro, R. J. (1991). â€Å"Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries.† Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106, 407-444. Barro, R. and X. Sala-i-Martin. (1992). â€Å"Convergence.† Journal of Political Economy, 100, 223- 51. Behrman, J., (1987). Commodity price instability and economic goal attainment in developing countries. World Development, 15(5), 559–573. Birdsall, N., Pinckney, T., Sabot, R., (2001). ‘‘Natural Resources, Human Capital, and Growth.’’ In Resource Abundance and Economic Development, ed. Richard M. Auty. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Bleaney, M., Nishiyama, A., (2002). ‘Explaining growth: a contest between models’, Journal of Economic Growth, 7(1), 43-56. Boschini, A., Petersson, J., Roine, J. (2007). ‘Resource curse or not: a question of appropriability’, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 109(3), 593-617. 18 Bravo-Ortega, C., Gregorio, J., 2007. The relative richness of the poorNatural resources, human capital and economic growth. In: Lederman, D., Maloney, W. (Eds.), Resources, Neither Curse nor Destiny. Stanford University Press, Washington, DC, Chapter 4, pp. 71- 99. Brunnschweiler, C. (2008). ‘Cursing the blessingsNatural resource abundance, institutions, and economic growth’, World Development, 36(3), 399-419. Brunnschweiler, C., Bulte, E. (2008). ‘The resource curse revisited and revised: a tale of paradoxes and red herrings’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 55(3), 248-264. Bulte, E., Damania, R. and Deacon, T. (2005), ‘Resource Intensity, Institutions, and Development’, World Development, 33(7), 1029–1044. Bulte, E. and R. Damania. (2008). â€Å"Resources for Sale: Corruption, Democracy and the Natural Resource Curse.† The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis Policy, 8(1), (Contributions), Article 5. Cotet, A., Tsui, K. (2010). ‘Resource curse or Malthusian trapEvidence from oil discoveries and extractions’, Ball University Economic Paper N? 201001. Davis, G. (1995). Learning to love the Dutch disease: evidence from the mineral economies. World Development 23(10), 1765-79. Davis, G.A. (2011). The resource drag. International Economics and Economic Policy 8, 155–176. Davis, J. (2001). Stabilization and savings funds for non-renewable resources: experience and fiscal policy implications (Washington D.C.: International Monetary Fund). Davis, J. (2003). Fiscal policy formulation and implementation in oil-producing countries (Washington D.C.: International Monetary Fund). Dawe, D. (1996). ‘A new look at the growth in developing countries’, World Development, 24(12), 1905-1914. Ding, N., Field, B.C. (2005). ‘‘Natural Resource Abundance and Economic Growth.’’ Land Economics, 81(4): 496–502. Dollar, D., Kraay, A., (2001). ‘‘Trade, Growth, and Poverty.’’ Policy Research Working Paper Series 2615. Washington, DC: World Bank. Fatas, A., Mihov, I. (2003). ‘The case for restricting fiscal policy discretion’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(4), 1419-1447. Fosu, A. (1996). Primary exports and economic growth in developing countries. World Economy, 19(4), 465–475. Gelb A.H. (1988). Oil windfalls: blessing or curseOxford University Press, New York. Gradstein, M. (2008), ’Institutional traps and economic growth’, International Economic Review, 49(3), 1043-66. Gylfason, T. (2001). Natural resources and economic growth; what is the connection’, CESifo Working Paper No. 50. Gylfason, T. (2001). ‘Natural resources, education and economic development’, European Economic Review, 45(4), 847-859. Hartford, T., Klein, M. (2005). ‘Aid and the resource curse’, The World Bank Group, Private Sector Development Presidency Note No. 291 (Washington, DC: World Bank). Hirschman, A., (1958). The strategy of economic development. Yale University Press, New Haven. Humphreys, M., Sachs, J., Stiglitz, J. (2007). Escaping the resource curse (New York: Columbia University Press). Isham, J., Woodcock, M., Pritchett, L.,Busby, G. (2005). ‘The varieties of resource experience: natural resource export structures and the political economy of economic growth’, World Bank Economic Review, 19(2), 141-174. Lederman, D., Maloney, W., (2003). ‘‘Trade Structure and Growth.’’ Policy Research Paper 3025. Washington, DC: World Bank. Leite, C., Weidmann, J. (2002), ‘Does mother nature corruptNatural resources, corruption and economic growth’, in G. Abed and S. Gupta (eds.), Governance, corruption, and economic performance (Washington DC: International Monetary Fund), 156–69. Lutz, M., (1994). ‘The effects of volatility in the terms of trade on output growth: New evidence,’ World Development, 22(12), 1959–1975. Manzano, O., Rigobon, R. (2006), ‘Resource curse or debt overhang?’, in D. Lederman and W. Maloney (eds.), Resources, neither curse nor destiny (Washington DC: Stanford University Press), 71-99. Matsuyama, K. (1992), ‘Agricultural Productivity, Comparative Advantage and Economic Growth’, Journal of Economic Theory, 58(2), 317-334. Mauro, P. (1995), ‘Corruption and Growth’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(3), 681- 712. Mehlum, H. Moene, K., Torvik, R. (2006), ‘Cursed by resources or institutions?’, The World Economy, 29(8), 1117-31. Meier, G., Rauch, J. (2000), Leading Issues in Economic Development (Oxford: Oxford University Press). Michaels, G., (2011). ‘The Long Term Consequences of Resource-Based Specialization’, Economic Journal, 121(551), 31-57. Papyrakis, E., Gerlagh, R. (2004). The resource curse hypothesis and its transmission channels. Journal of Comparative Economics 32(1), 181-193. Papyrakis, E. and R. Gerlagh. (2007). â€Å"Resource Abundance and Economic Growth in the U.S.† European Economic Review, 51(4), 1011-1039. Ross, M. L. (2001), ‘Does oil hinder democracy?’, World Politics, 53(3), 325–361. Robinson, James A., Ragnar Torvik, and Thierry Verdier. 2006. ‘‘Political Foundations of the Resource Curse.’’ Journal of Development Economics 79(2), 447–68. Sachs, J.D. and A.M. Warner. (1995). â€Å"Natural Resource Abundance and Economic Growth.† National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 5398, December. Sachs, J., Warner, A. (2001), ‘The curse of natural resources’, European Economic Review, 45(4), 827-38. Sala-i-Martin, X., Subramanian, A. (2003). ‘Addressing the natural resource curse: an illustration from Nigeria’, NBER Working Paper No. 9804. Smith, A., [1776]1976. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Campbell, R.H., Skinner, A.S., Todd, W.B. (Eds.). Clarendon Press, Oxford. Stein, E., Tommasi, M., Echebarria, K, Lora, E., Payne, M. (2005), The politics of policies:economic and social progress in Latin America (Washington DC: IDB). Torres, N., Afonso, O., Soares, I. (forthcoming). Oil abundance and Economic Growth – A Panel Data Analysis. Forthcoming in Energy Journal. Stern, N. (2008). ‘The economics of climate change’, American Economic Review, 98(2), 1-37. Stijns, J. (2005). Natural resource abundance and economic growth revisited. Resources policy, 30(2), 107-30. Torvik, R. (2002). ‘Natural resource rent seeking and welfare’, Journal of Development Economics, 67(2), 455-70. Tsui, K. (2011), ‘More oil, less democracy: evidence from worldwide crude oil discoveries’, Economic Journal, 121(551), 89-115. Van der Ploeg, F., and Poelhekke, S. (2010), ‘The pungent smell of ‘red herrings’: subsoil assets, rents, volatility and the resource curse’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 60(1), 44-55. Wheeler D. (1984). Sources of stagnation in sub-Saharan Africa. World Development, 12(1), 1–23. Wright, G., Czelusta, J. (2004). ‘‘The Myth of the Resource Curse.’’ Challenge, 47(2), 6–38. How to cite Theories on Resource Curse, Essay examples

Friday, December 6, 2019

The Last Czar Essay Research Paper The free essay sample

The Last Czar Essay, Research Paper The Last Czar Have you of all time heard of Gregory Efimovich Rasputin, the sanctum adult male, the mad monastic? The first clip I heard of the huffy monastic and his engagement within the Alexandra Palace in Tsarkoe, Selo I was truly moved by the bend of events ; that lead to the overthrow of the Russian imperial system, the deposition of the House of Romanov and the blackwash of the Imperial Family. The huffy monastic was in the highest circles of St. Petersburg society, and captured the attending of the higher reverends of the Russian Empire. The monastic performed his miracles within the castle on the imperial twosome s boy, Tsarevich Alexis Nicholaievich, who was born with Hemophilia. In my narrative of the huffy monastic and the imperial household you will larn why the mad monastic was loved, and why he was hated in the circles he traveled. We will write a custom essay sample on The Last Czar Essay Research Paper The or any similar topic specifically for you Do Not WasteYour Time HIRE WRITER Only 13.90 / page I will besides uncover the dark side of this alleged sanctum adult male ; one of a adult male with a debauched, and eternal sexual appetency. Undoubtedly, the Empress Alexandra neer had dealingss of a sexual nature with Rasputin ; he was a therapist to her boy, Alex, the inheritor to the throne, when he had a hemorrhage crisis. Alexandra put her religion into Rasputin, she became dependent on him, and she saw no incorrect in the his ways. Many of the Orthodox reverends became disbelieving of the monastic and his close engagement with the imperial household, the Romanov household members of Tsarevich Nicholas Alexandrovich besides became concerned and wanted him to be sent off. With many prayers from Tsars Nicholas s household to direct the monastic off, Nicholas was so in love with Alexandra, that he could non direct the monastic off for fright of his boy shed blooding to decease and his household falling to pieces. Rasputin had great influence over the imperial household, and his a ctions doing indignation, gave a disgraceful image to the imperial household. Without hold, from rumours about the monastic, and his drunken parties, of wild sexual behaviour, Nicholas punished Rasputin by directing him back to the states. Rasputin as summoned by Alexandra non long after his going, when the Empresses boy had another hemorrhage crisis. A penitent Rasputin, was neer once more challenged and his behaviour remained every bit iniquitous as of all time. Rumors of Rasputin ranged anyplace from him holding binges in his cellar to holding sex with cocottes. Despite the monastic s imbibing turns, and philandering ways, Rasputin remained in high circles. Consequently, some of the household members of the Romanov s took affairs in to their ain custodies and plotted to assassinate the monastic. The slayers were believed to hold been the Tsra s cousin, the Grand Duke Dimitri Pavlovich, and the Prince Felix Youssoupov. Rasputin was invited by Youssoupov to his huge Petrograd castle on December 16, 1916. Rasputin ate tea biscuits, and drank vino ; any of which were filled with adequate nitrile to hold killed six work forces. When the huffy monastic did non decease from the toxicant, he was so changeable. Rasputin gained consciousness and crawled his last stairss to the gate of the entryway of the Petrograd castle, where he was so changeable and beaten. Rasputin s organic structure was found in icy H2O s of Neva on December 19. Rasputin s bonds were broken upon find. This indicated that he did non decease until his organic structure was submerged into the icy Waterss, and his lungs filled with H2O, submerging him. Furthermore, Nicholas and Alexandra exiled the plotters and said that no penalty could of all time be excessively great for the offenses they committed. Alexandra read a missive from Rasputin written merely before he died. In the missive, he said that he knew his life would stop in a few yearss, and if anyone else besides her household killed him, she would be safe ; but if it was her household who killed him, within two old ages her whole household would be dead. After the decease of Rasputin Nicholas lost his throne, and some of the Romanov cousins were killed by a Bolshevik fire squad. The Tsar s household, and their staff were imprisoned in a house in Ekatinburg. On July 16, 1918 The Tsar, Aleaxandra, their 14 twelvemonth old boy, their four girls, and staff members were taken into a half cellar room and killed by a Bolshevik secret constabulary firing squad. The organic structures have neer received a proper entombment, and today the castanetss remain in cellar.